In his article in Sunday’s New York Times Magazine section (4.15.07), “Is Justin Timberlake a Product of Cumulative Advantage? A new theory of the hit record,” Duncan Watts makes two startling claims about movie, book, and music hits: they don’t really reflect what most people want (i.e., their actual preferences) and they are inherently unpredictable. This is bad news for those who pour millions into marketing products in these industries, but Watts goes further, suggesting that business products in general, from software to organic food, suffer from the same problem.
The reason prediction is supposedly hard (if not impossible) is that market success can be shown to depend not primarily on perceived quality by a majority of consumers, but rather on social influence, which quickly overwhelms such perceptions. In this age of excessive choice, people are rarely able to make up their minds about what they like on the basis of their own judgment. Instead, they allow themselves to be swayed by what other people say, i.e., the buzz. The result is that “the rich get richer.” Like the famous “butterfly effect” from chaos theory, over time, even a small, virtually random variation in initial buzz can have a huge impact, translating into the difference between a megahit and being located somewhere far down the infamous long tail of non-hits.
Watts’s claims clearly offend common sense: Was Harry Potter primarily the outcome of initial successful buzz? Could the Beatles have remained stuck playing in the Cavern Club in Liverpool but for some chance advantage in word of mouth about “I Want to Hold Your Hand”? Did the Apple iPod get over 70% market share based mostly on the word of early adopters? Watts roundly dismisses our touching belief in the idea that markets largely reflect our preferences as consisting of stories we make up afterwards to satisfy “our desire to believe in an orderly universe.” But in advancing his theory, Watts is not just ignoring our own intuitions as consumers, but network science itself.
The rich-get-richer effect Watts bases his argument on was in fact first formulated (as Watts acknowledges in Six Degrees) by Albert-László Barabási as the outcome of a law of preferential attachment: we tend to choose things that are already popular—in network terms, connect to nodes that are already highly linked. However, as Barabási points out in Linked: The New Science of Networks, the effect, while undoubtedly having some truth to it, fails in many cases, being superceded by a different effect: the fit get rich. That explains why, for example, a late-entry search-engine like Google could still trounce its competitors long after the rich-get-richer effect should have locked the market up. It was simply a much better—fitter—product.
Similarly (for details, see my Smart World, Chapter 5), the rich-get-richer effect explains the initial success of the MITS Altair as the first real microcomputer, but it was the Apple II’s superior fitness (i.e., match to emerging customer preferences) that enabled it to sweep all before it. Most real hits, whether it’s the Beatles or Harry Potter or the iPod, are the result of better market fit with consumer wants, not initial richness of buzz, and to that extent are partly predictable. Watts’s claims regarding the impact of buzz and the consequent unpredictability of hits work in markets where (as in the case of his carefully controlled experiment on producing hit records) competing products are qualitatively hard to distinguish from one another—a hardly surprising result. But plenty of market competitions aren’t like that, and then another network law comes into play.
That’s not the end of the story, by the way. We can further refine our conception of how hits happen with another effect—the fit get fitter, a sort of Darwinian law of quality. But I’ll save that for another blog…
I think you're making a very common error of determinism in advancing this argument. I would suggest that there is no one determinant of systemic change or effect in a human system that is governed by principles of complexity. Although fitness as you describe it does indeed play an important role in the ultimate success of any endeavour or product, it is not the sole determinant, nor often even the most important one. Although one counter-example does not an argument make, consider the case of the various office suites that emerged and failed before the overwhelming success and industry dominance of Microsoft Office. In fact, many Microsoft products are not the most fit for the task, but they do dominate - for other reasons - in the marketing ecosystem.
Of equal interest in this regard is Granovetter's 1973 work "The Strength of Weak Ties," not to mention Castell's scholarship in his trilogy from the mid-1990s. I would also suggest that the theory of "the fit get fitter" might be somewhat rebutted by Clayton Christensen's "Innovator's Dilemma" in which he demonstrates how those organizations that are most fit ultimately fail in their ability to innovate and remain current, or indeed, relevant.
Posted by: Mark Federman | June 29, 2007 at 12:07 PM
Very good blog, was happy to learn a lot here, I hope I can often look, thank you very much!
Posted by: chaussure lacoste | May 28, 2012 at 05:25 AM
Not only can you hear some of the most interesting commercials and/or movies also. Learning music helps increase songs starting with x your concentration levels. In the world of professional music making. There are sleepers, non-sleepers, criers, those that need their backs rubbed, and those that need special blankets from home. EditingIf you are familiar with family bands such as Jefferson Airplane, T Rex, Mud, and Wizard as well as the first note of the major factors of concentration is the person's arousal level.
Posted by: Lyrics | October 01, 2013 at 02:15 PM